The principles of economics explain the world...or at least most of it.
Underwriting
the Next Housing Crisis
By PETER J. WALLISON
OCT. 31, 2014
WASHINGTON — SEVEN
years after the housing bubble burst, federal regulators backed
away this month from the tougher mortgage-underwriting standards that the
Dodd-Frank Act of 2010 had directed them to develop. New standards were
supposed to raise the quality of the “prime” mortgages that get packaged and
sold to investors; instead, they will have the opposite effect.
Responding to the
law, federal regulators proposed tough new standards in 2011, but after
bipartisan outcries from Congress and fierce lobbying by interested parties,
including community activists, the Obama administration and the real estate and
banking industries — all eager to increase home sales — the standards have been
watered down. The regulators had wanted a down payment of 20 percent, a good
credit record and a maximum debt-to-income ratio of 36 percent. But under
pressure, they dropped the down payment and good-credit requirements and agreed
to a debt-to-income limit as high as 43 percent.
The regulators
believe that lower underwriting standards promote homeownership and make
mortgages and homes more affordable. The facts, however, show that the opposite
is true.
In the late ’80s and
early ’90s, down payments were 10 to 20 percent. The homeownership rate was 64
percent — about where it is now — and nearly 90 percent of housing markets were
considered affordable (that is, home prices were no more than three times
family income). By 2011 only 50 percent were considered affordable, and by
2014, just 36 percent — even though down payments as low as 5 percent are now
common.
How could this be?
Consider this: If the required down payment for a mortgage is 10 percent, a
potential home buyer with $10,000 can purchase a $100,000 home. But if the down
payment is dropped to 5 percent, the same buyer can purchase a $200,000 home.
The buyer is taking more risk by borrowing more, but can afford to bid more.
In other words, low
underwriting standards — especially low down payments — drive housing prices
up, making them less affordable for low- and moderate-income buyers, while also
inducing would-be homeowners to take more risk.
That’s why homes were
more affordable before the 1990s than they are today. Back then, when
traditional standards for “prime” mortgages prevailed, homes were smaller; they
had fewer bathrooms, and the kitchens were not appointed by Martha Stewart. A
family could buy and live in a “starter home” for several years before selling
it and using the accumulated equity to buy a bigger or better appointed home.
In a competitive
housing market not subsidized by lax standards, home builders would similarly
adjust by reducing the size and amenities of new homes to meet the financial
resources of home buyers entering the market. Home prices would stabilize and
not rise faster than incomes. Low- and moderate-income families and millennials
might have to wait to save for a first home, but they would be able to afford
it.
(Higher down payments
are not the only way to limit excessive borrowing. The “standard” 30-year
mortgage is a subsidized, archaic result of our government’s distorted housing
policies; very few home buyers stay in a home for 30 years. A 15-year
fixed-rate mortgage means higher monthly payments, but the homeowner starts to
accumulate equity sooner, reducing the lender’s risk.)
If the government got
out of the way, would sound underwriting standards come back? History suggests
yes. Although Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were government-backed,
they were shareholder-owned, profit-making firms. They adopted strong
underwriting standards to avoid the credit risk of subprime and other high-risk
mortgages. But after Congress enacted affordable-housing goals, administered by
the Department of Housing and Urban Development, in 1992, underwriting
standards declined.
Republicans generally
favor eliminating the government’s role in housing finance, while Democrats
worry that without government support, mortgages would be too expensive for
low- and moderate-income families. Although it runs counter to the current
Washington view, good underwriting standards can satisfy the objectives of both
parties.
It’s clear that
today’s policies create winners and losers. The winners include real estate
agents and home builders, who want to increase borrowing and sell ever-larger
and more expensive homes. The losers, as we saw in the financial crisis, are
borrowers of modest means who are lured into financing arrangements they can’t
afford. When the result is foreclosure and eviction, one of the
central goals of homeownership — building equity — is undone.
After the financial
crisis, Representative Barney Frank — the Massachusetts Democrat who led the
House Financial Services Committee during the crisis, and a champion of credit
programs for low-income buyers — admitted, “It was a great mistake to push
lower-income people into housing they couldn’t afford and couldn’t really
handle once they had it.” Policy makers who support homeownership would be wise
to consider who is hurt and who is helped when we abandon traditional
underwriting standards.
Peter J. Wallison, a senior fellow at the American Enterprise Institute,
is the author of the forthcoming book “Hidden in Plain Sight: What Really
Caused the World’s Worst Financial Crisis and Why It Could Happen Again.”
1 comment:
Dr. Parker,
Thanks for sharing. This reminds me of "Fault Lines". Pretty good book if you have not read it.
Post a Comment